Skip to main content

No Copyright - No music? (article excerpt)


Introduction

To what extent does copyright law encourage the production of music? On the one hand, the Internet features a vast amount of new music, while on the other hand copyright law is practically weakened by piracy. This is a paradoxical situation. Following the rationale of copyrights, a mitigation of the law (due to problems of enforceability) should lead to a decrease in musical output due to lack of incentives and vice versa. This paper analyzes the motivational incentive of copyrights to artists and labels to produce and publish music.

Conclusion

A sagging copyright (due to piracy) should lead to a decreasing number in music recordings. However, in light of the flourishing supply of new music on the Internet, something in this equation appears to be wrong.

Firstly, artists appear not to be influenced significantly by copyrights. The majority of artists would not adjust their musical productivity to copyright alterations. In addition, there is evidence of a cost-of-creation effect shown by a contrary reaction of some artists to copyright modifications—meaning, the weaker copyrights are, the more music some artists would produce.

Secondly, even though the overall number of record labels which would react in line with copyright modifications is relatively small, they seem to be more sensitive to copyright alterations than artists. While around 7% of the artists indicated to adapt their output in line with copyright modifications, around 17% of the labels would react in such way. In addition, similar to the case of artists, there is evidence of a cost-of-creation effect in the case of the labels as well.

Thirdly, these results experience support by the analysis of the artist’s and record label’s opinions toward copyright infringements. While around 80% of the artists do not support severe penalties for copyright infringements, only 50% of the record labels indicated such behavior.

These findings are consistent with previous research which found only little evidence for the incentive effects of copyrights to produce art. The overall results show that even without a copyright there will be plenty of artists and a hand full of record labels which produce and market music. However, this present study emphasizes that there is a significant gap between the artist’s and label’s opinion toward copyrights. It appears that a strong copyright fosters the industry side of the value-creation chain in the music industry more than the creation side represented by the artists. Following this logic, it seems understandable that parallel to the multiple extensions of international copyright laws a strong and professionalized-shaped music industry has evolved.

On the contrary, a weak copyright should lead to a trend to amateurism. Exactly this is what can be observed over the last approximately ten years. The mitigation of copyright law in the wake of piracy (in particular its enforcement) led to a, in the words of Schumpeter, “creative destruction.” According to the results of this study, artists continue to produce music even without significant copyright earnings. We see an increase of self-marketing artist-entrepreneurs and a decrease in revenues in the professional industry. Due to the fact that these days artists can enter the market and distribute their work over the Internet easily and single-handedly, a different business environment in market for music recordings arises. We see a shift from professionalism to amateurism, from maximizing profits to maximizing creative expression, from full-time label-signed artists to part-time self-marketing artists-entrepreneurs. Accordingly, the initially stated paradoxical situation about a weak copyright but a flourishing music supply is explainable.

Nevertheless this should not be understood as a recommendation to weaken or abolish copyrights in the music industry. This paper just shows that the regulating mechanism of copyrights has different effects on different market participants. In the controversial debate about the bargaining function of copyrights, this information is crucial to evaluate each side—access to culture versus incentives to produce creative goods. Furthermore an interesting issue arises in the question whether an environment of amateurs and semi-professionals will produce music of inferior quality than a professionalized industry. Future research will assist in completing this picture.

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Bibliography of my thesis 'Artist Entrepreneurship In The Music Industry'

Ackerman-Haywood, J. (2010). Artist follows inner drive toward full-time art career. The Grand Rapids Press.  Retrieved January 3, 2012, from http://blog.mlive.com/runningwithneedles/2010/10/artist_follows_inner_drive_tow.html Adler, M. (2006). Stardom and talent. Handbook on the Economics of Art and Culture, 1, 895-906.   Adler, N. E., Epel, E. S., Castellazzo, G., & Ickovics, J. R. (2000). Relationship of subjective and objective social status with psychological and physiological functioning: Preliminary data in healthy, White women. Health Psychology, 19(6), 586.   Adorno, T., & Horkheimer, M. (1977). The Culture Industry: enlightenment as mass deception. In J. Curran, M. Gurevitch & J. Woollacott (Eds.), Mass Communication and Society (pp. 349-389). London: Edward Arnold in association with The Open University Press.   Adorno, T. W. (1941). On popular music. Studies in Philosophy and Social Science, 9(1), 17–48.   Ahlkvist, J. A., & Fisher, G. (2000). And the hits

Digital Distribution Models Reviewed: The Content Provider’s Perspective (book chapter)

Citation (APA): Peltz, P. (2013). Digital Distribution Models Reviewed: The Content Provider’s Perspective . In Music Business and the Experience Economy (pp. 99-117). Springer Berlin Heidelberg. Abstract Digital distribution has surpassed physical distribution in key markets and will soon be the dominant music distribution model in Australia. Four different business models (free, ad-funded, pay-per-use and subscription-based) and two different music delivery methods (downloading and streaming) currently compete in the market place. The author analyses each distribution model available in Australia and evaluates advantages and disadvantages from the content provider’s perspective. The most striking development is the blurring line between promotion and distribution. Content providers can either lower the barriers to access music in order to facilitate rapid music circulation and create a strong promotional effect to support various revenue streams; or heighten the barriers to acc

Why Theodore W. Adorno would follow Chris Anderson on Twitter (essay)

Introduction At first glance, the reader may wonder what Theodore W. Adorno and Chris Anderson have in common and what that has to do with researching the music industry. On the one hand, a sophisticated German philosopher; a critical theorist of the 20th century; a member of the renowned Frankfurt School and a follower of Karl Marx’s thoughts on capitalism and society. On the other, Chris Anderson, a child of the digital economy, a blog writer, a journalist, a business entrepreneur and, according to The Time 100 , one of the most influential thinkers of the new millennium. Both were (respectively are) critically reflecting the media landscape of their time. In this paper I use the ideas of both thinkers and demonstrate the Mediamorphosis in the wake of technological innovations at the example of the music industry. On the one hand a centralized media system dominated by large media conglomerates, on the other side a democratic media system driven by prosumers. Thes two contrasting m